Whilst the expert panel dictated that most tasks would be subject to productivity gains over the next decade, i.e. a negative displacement effect, some tasks would see an increase in demand for workers as a necessary corollary of achieving those productivity gains. An example is that workers would have to ‘interact more with computers’, in order to achieve technology-based productivity gains in other tasks, such as ‘inspecting equipment’. These “positive displacements” are interpreted differently to negative displacements. They are interpreted solely as a change in the task-composition of an occupation, which results in a rise in aggregate hours the worker spends on that task at the expense of other tasks, such that the net FTE employment for the occupation is unchanged. Therefore, the total displacement effect for each individual occupation is always non-positive. For interacting with computers specifically, an additional assumption is imposed, stating that this task becomes important for more jobs, based on an adjustment in the importance threshold for this task.15
Modelling the income effect
The income effect occurs as a result of increased demand for goods and services and offsets the displacement effect on employment. Where that demand falls, i.e. how people spend their extra income – is independent of where technology is generating productivity gains. To estimate the income effect, we took GVA growth forecasts for Australia from the Oxford Economics Global Industry Model and derived the implications for individual occupations using the industry-occupation employment matrices.
In the real world, the displacement and income effect occur in parallel. However, technically we estimated the displacement effect of our technology scenario first. We take the post-displacement employment for occupation o in industry ( ), then apply the GVA forecast for industry ( )16 and sum across all industries to estimate the net change in employment level for occupation o ( ).